This piece has been published in India Together under the title "From mandi's to markets: Will this round be any better?"
Farmers across the country are extremely agitated.
Farmers across the country are extremely agitated.
A quick scan of just the English language
media – which typically does not show much interest in rural India – reveals
the numerous protests in which they have taken part, among the recent being the
long march to Mumbai by tens of thousands of farmers. More protests are
expected in the coming days.
Common to all the protests are the demands
for a complete loan waiver and fair prices for farm produce. As an earlier
piece explains, the returns to the farmer are barely
sufficient to sustain him and often below the cost he incurs. At the same time,
wholesale traders bringing the farmer’s produce to the consumer enjoy hefty
margins unjustified by the value they add. The market has failed the Indian
farmer and this is at the root of the farm crisis.
How is this situation to be remedied? There
are two diametrically opposing views.
One view is that the state must accept responsibility for the well being of the
farmer and weigh in on the side of the farmer to compensate for the
fundamental asymmetry in the economic standing of farmers and traders.
The other view derives from an unquestioning
belief in the efficacy of the free market. It is useful to consider this in
some detail because of the influence it has on policy makers.
The
free market vision
‘Free marketers’ believe that state
interventions and controls in the agriculture market have distorted prices. Freed
from these, the market itself would enable true price discovery and improve the
terms of trade for farmers.
The specific interventions that India’s
free marketers would like to see ended are the state declaring Minimum Support
Prices (MSPs), procuring grains and pulses, regulating wholesale trade with
farmers, controlling stocks with traders and controlling exports.
But this is not all. The free marketers
would like the state to “free” land markets too so that farm land can be sold
or leased freely. This would enable aggregation (by buying or renting) of farm
land into large farms. An editorial
in Livemint (Mar 21, 2018) lays out the wish list of the free marketers in
full.
The United States is possibly the
inspiration for these free marketers.
The US has 2.1 million farms compared to
India’s 90 million. Just 8% of farms that are >1000 acres in size account
for 70% of overall farmland (US
Census of Agriculture). The large farm sizes are possible because 40% of
farmland is leased. In the US, the agricultural supply chain is dominated by
massive companies such as Cargill, ADM and Bunge whose operations range from
global trading in agricultural commodities to transforming crops into packaged
products for supermarket shelves.
In the world of agriculture envisioned by
the free marketers, India would have far fewer farmers and a large fraction of
agricultural land consolidated into large farms. Corporations trading in and
processing food would be directly able to deal with farmers and the government
would have no influence or control on the price of agricultural commodities.
But how would the farmers ousted from agriculture
find alternate livelihoods when there are no jobs even for the youth entering
the labour force? The free marketers will not be bothered by such questions.
While the present Indian government does
not want to give up its ability to influence price and availability of
agricultural commodities (by doing away with MSP, procurement and export
controls), it has bought into the prescriptions of the free marketers to dismantle
existing regulations governing wholesale purchases from farmers. Before delving
into how this is driving policy, a brief introduction to the existing
agriculture supply chain structure will be useful.
Mandis and their
regulatory capture
The wholesale purchase of produce from
farmers in India is governed by the Agricultural Produce Marketing Committee
(APMC) Act. Agriculture is a state subject and each state has its own version
of the law based on the template put out by the centre.
According to the APMC Act, wholesale
transactions between farmers and traders must take place in designated market
yards (mandis) and follow certain
rules. These yards have been established throughout the country in agricultural
production centres. The yards are managed by an elected authority with
government supervision.
The concerns of this law can be better
understood when seen in the context of the 60’s and 70’s when the APMC’s were
set up. Small farmers were extremely vulnerable to being cheated by agents who
would purchase their produce locally in the village. In the APMC yards, farmers
got a better feel for the price. The sale of produce under public scrutiny
brought a level of protection against being cheated on weights and measures and
price. The APMC markets were clearly an advance on the situation prevailing
earlier. Most trading shifted to the regulated mandis though there is still a significant fraction that takes place in the
villages.
Over time, traders have established their
control over the regulated markets. That this has happened is not hard to
understand if one takes into account the huge asymmetry in the economic
standing of traders and farmers.
The market committees are elected bodies
and APMC elections too are fought with political affiliations. Traders with
their economic power and ties to the major political parties end up controlling
the committees. Government supervision is weak at best and cannot stand up to
the economic and political clout of traders. Traders can cartelize with ease
and set prices for agricultural produce right in the face of regulations meant
for farmer’s protection.
Farmers are unable to stand up to this
cartelization. They lack pricing power as suppliers. Added to this, they are
often beholden to traders who help them through the production cycle with short
term loans, transport and storage. Though aware that prices are fixed, they
have no option other than to play along.
Reforming
the mandis through competition
The government acknowledges the
cartelization that happens in APMC markets right under state supervision.
However, it does not want to acknowledge this as a governance failure. Instead,
in line with the thinking of the free marketers, it argues that what is
necessary are alternate channels which can compete with the regulated APMC mandis for farmer’s produce. This
competition, it is claimed, will lead to farmers getting better prices and more
investment flowing into the agriculture supply chain. This is thinking is
behind the new (model) agricultural
produce and livestock marketing (APLM) Act of 2017 that the present central
government has unveiled.
The Prime Minister was reported
to have written to the chief ministers of states recently emphasising the need
to “swiftly undertake market reforms of our decades old and restricted
agriculture produce and marketing committee (APMC) architecture”. The
government is clearly in a hurry to get the states to adopt the new law which
will replace the APMC Acts.
The alternative channels to APMC markets for
farmers are to be privately managed markets and farmer-consumer markets. But
most importantly, large buyers such as firms engaged in food processing, large
scale retail or exports will be able to bypass the wholesale markets and buy
directly from the farmer.
Actually, all the above measures to “free”
the agricultural market are old hat. Back in 2003, the then BJP government put
together a ‘model’ regulation (APMC Act 2003) for allowing alternate channels
in agricultural marketing and the Congress government notified the rules to go
with the regulation in 2007.
26 states have since carried out modifications to
their state specific APMC Acts in line with this model Act. Bihar has gone to the extent of getting rid of the APMC regulated
markets altogether to allow free private play.
What has been the impact of these changes
on the markets?
Private markets have been a non-starter.
While a number of licences have been issued in Maharashtra and a few in
Karnataka, Gujarat and Andhra, most licensees do not seem to be operating
markets on the ground. It seems no one wants
to invest in setting up market yards just to earn the market fee of 2% of
transaction value.
Bihar too has seen no
investment in private market infrastructure. As reported in the Hindu Business Line (Feb 8, 2015), trade happens
in informal makeshift markets that have no facilities and no competitive price
discovery; their only advantage seems to be the ease of access for farmers.
There are
farmer-consumer markets in several states – AP, Tamil Nadu, Punjab, Haryana –
variously named rythu bazar, apni mandi, etc. They have not made a
difference as a whole as few farmers can afford to take their produce to these
markets which need to be located near cities.
What about the ‘direct marketing licences’
issued to large firms to procure directly from farmers?
Maharashtra has been in the forefront
giving licences to many large firms including Tatas,
Aditya Birla, Reliance, Big Bazaar, ITC, ADM Agro and Mahindra & Mahindra.
But as of 2016, their purchases represented only a tiny fraction of the total
purchases from farmers - 1000 crore annually against 60-75,000 crore
transactions in APMC mandi’s and
25,000 crore in village and other informal markets (Indian
Express, July 21, 2016). Big retailers,
it appears, prefer to recruit existing middlemen as their agents and buy in the
APMC markets. This is not surprising, for which corporation would like to
directly deal with lakhs of small farmers?
Pinning
the hope on big corporations
The government is acutely aware of the failure
of the previous reforms. There is no private investment flowing into public use
infrastructure that can benefit the farmers. Neither is there any movement
towards farmers getting fair prices. The government however argues that this is
because private firms wishing to set up alternate channels still do not have a
“level playing field”.
With this argument, the APLM Act 2017 goes
beyond the earlier reforms to make things extremely attractive for private firms
wanting to enter the agricultural
supply chain.
Under
existing law, states are territorially divided into market areas and the market
committees constituted under the APMC Act exercise regulatory functions (such
as collecting market fees) over their respective market areas. This also places
certain constraints on the movement of agricultural produce across market area
boundaries.
The
new law confines the role of these market committees to within the publicly
owned mandis. Licensing and regulation
of private firms and traders is vested with the state government and licensed
entities can operate anywhere within the state.
The
government claims that the new law by allowing the farmer to sell anywhere in
the state and to whomever he chooses will help the farmer realize better
prices. The fact is that farmers have difficulty transporting their produce
even to the nearest market yard. It is the private firms and traders who will
now have the freedom to buy anywhere and profit from arbitrage.
Further,
while traders must still operate within private or public market yards, licensed
firms can make their purchases in front of the existing market yards without any
need for investing in private yards. They have to pay a market fee only 1/4th
of what is charged in the market yards. It is not clear by what logic this
number was arrived at. There are also no transparency requirements imposed on
them in respect of trades.
In
summary, the APLM Act 2017 goes all out to help corporations entering the food
chain to buy direct from the farmers by allowing them unfettered access to
aggregation centres (the existing market yards) throughout the state for a
token market fee, without having to invest in their own yards.
Will
the entry of a new class of buyers help farmer producers realize a better
price?
The
fact is that the basic lack of pricing power among farmers does not change when
they deal with corporations instead of traders. The experience of the last 11
years shows that corporations tend to merge into the existing supply chain at
the last mile to the farmer. There is no reason to assume that the margins they
make because of bringing in greater efficiency in the supply chain will be
shared with farmers. Corporate India is not going to come to the rescue of
India’s farmers.
The
2003 APMC reforms did not lead to any appreciable improvement in the lives of farmers;
neither will the APML Act 2017 being pushed by the present government. These
reforms are not about helping farmers realize better prices, but about opening
up more opportunities for corporate India.
No comments:
Post a Comment