My India Together article on this subject can be seen here. Reproduced below
01 October 2007
SEZs: A history of injustice and abuse
The current
government overdrive on Special Economic Zones has once again brought to the
fore the question of where the line is to be drawn between public good and
private profit. Whereas the law allows Central and State governments, as well
as private developers, to set up SEZs, in practice it is the latter group that
has proposed the majority of these zones. That being the case, a number of
questions have come up, that point to the divergence between the role that
governments are supposed to play in promoting public good, and their actual
conduct in facilitating the establishment of SEZs.
Some of these
questions are now centre-stage in the debate. Is it right for state governments
to expropriate land from farmers or should land acquisition be the
responsibility of private developers and subject to market forces? Who does the
state bear greater responsibility towards - the farmers and other villagers who
will lose their livelihoods as a result of establishment of these zones, or the
private developers of these zones?
Two principal
questions
Acquiring the
land is the biggest incentive held out to private SEZ developers by the state
governments. The state involvement becomes more apparent in the larger zones
that are in the land acquisition phase. Nandigram is by now famous as an example
of a failed forced acquisition. However, this has not deterred the West Bengal
government from looking at other areas in the state for the same SEZ and for
acquisition for the Haldia SEZ. In Maharashtra, the state government has
transferred lands acquired by CIDCO to the Navi-Mumbai SEZ, while it has been
actively acquiring land for Reliance for the Maha-Mumbai SEZ. And in the north,
there is the example of the Reliance Haryana SEZ where the state government and
Reliance together have signed agreement for developing what is billed as the
largest SEZ in India.
All the above
cases reinforce the idea that large sized SEZs implicitly depend on the state
to provide land. Governments, increasingly challenged over their roles in
acquiring land for private development, argue that SEZs are needed for the
'development' of their states, and that they need to do everything possible to
attract the promoters of these zones to their own state. Whether SEZs will
bring in the promised benefits is an entirely different discussion. What is
examined here is the injustice of using the colonial land acquisition law that
has become such a favourite instrument in the hands of state governments.
A second
pertinent question relates to the economic philosophy behind SEZs. In the last
two decades, we have witnessed a profusion of support for 'free markets'. The
Prime Minister is hailed routinely as the primary architect of pro-market
'reforms' during this period. But SEZs challenge that reading of recent
history, and prompts us to ask whether 'pro-business' - rather than
'pro-market' - is a more accurate description of attidues to the economy within
government since the early 90s. In the case of SEZs, governments are
practically over-ruling market forces in determing the price of land being
acquired. The additional irony is that the private industry that is usually
vocal against the 'licence and permit raj' desires, nay, needs, the state
governments to acquire land.
Eminent domain
The origins of
the land acquisition act can be traced to 1824, when the British colonial power
felt the need to codify in law what was earlier undisguised forcible seizure of
land. The Bengal Regulation I of 1824 was based on the principle of 'eminent
domain' - the power of the state to take any private property for public use -
and enabled land to be acquired for roads, canals and other public works. This
was extended to cover land acquisition for the railways in 1850. Separate laws
that had evolved in the territories around Calcutta, Bombay and Madras were consolidated
into a single law applicable to all the territories of British India by 1857.
In 1870, the rules for determination of
compensation for the land acquired based on 'market value' were defined, a
'solatium' (additional compensation over market value in view of the
involuntary nature of parting with the land) introduced, and the right of
appeal to civil court in case of dispute over compensation provided. This law
evolved over a period of time under British rule and took the consolidated form
of the 'Land Acquisition Act 1894', which has remained almost unchanged to this
day.
What were the
key concerns of the colonial legislators? The state had to be able to acquire
land for a 'public purpose' quickly and easily; excessive compensation, seen as
wastage of government resources, was to be avoided. The law was framed with
exactly the above concerns in view. The imperial stance was evident in one
simple fact - 'public purpose' was neither defined nor elaborated by the law;
it was sufficient for the state to declare it to be so. Further, elaborate
rules were framed for determining compensation and ensuring that payouts deemed
to be 'excessive' did not happen.
The end of
colonial rule in 1947 and the republican constitution of 1950 did not bring
about any significant change in the land acquisition law. The Constitution of
India, by article 372, allowed all colonial laws to remain in force unless they
were explicitly repealed. There was an enormous increase in infrastructure
building and industrial activities by the state as compared to the colonial
period. Numerous large dams, power plants, mines, steel and heavy engineering
plants came up over land acquired using the 1894 law, causing a massive
displacement of small farmers, agricultural labour, landless village workers
and artisans and forest dwellers. The number of people displaced by projects
and those whose livelihood was affected between 1951 and 1995 has been
estimated at 50 million by some social scientists based on detailed studies.
Rehabilitation,
inadequate in the best of cases, was mostly absent. Compensation followed the
requirements of the colonial land law and was available to only those who could
show ownership of land. Compensation was pegged to 'market' value; however,
given that the land market in India was not developed for a number of reasons,
and given that recorded transactions invariably undervalued real market rates -
and do so to this day - this did not address the issue of fair compensation.
With the result that the acquirer of land continued to be privileged under the
law, as in colonial times.
'Public
purpose' and private industry
Public sector
and government projects were not the only purposes for which land was forcibly
acquired by the state. Even in the Nehruvian period, land was being acquired
for private industry by state governments. A landmark judgement (R.L Aurora vs. State of
U.P, 1962) of the
Supreme Court held that the government could not justify acquiring land for a
textile machinery manufacturer as a 'public purpose'. It further declared that
"the Land Acquisition Act did not contemplate that the Government should
be made a general agent for companies to acquire lands for them for their
private profit".
That might have
been an opportunity to revise the injustices of the Act, but in the event, the
Nehru government chose to do the opposite. The immediate response of the
government was to amend the law through the Land Acquisition (Amendment) Act
1962 to allow land to be acquired for a company "which is engaged in or is
taking steps for engaging in any industry or work for a public purpose" . This
was applied with retrospective effect and superseded the earlier Supreme Court
judgement. Thus the Nehruvian era state succeeded in preserving its authority
for acquiring land for private industry. Subsequently, in the courts, a variety
of projects of private enterprise for diverse purposes - houses for members of
a co-operative society, manufacture of alumina bricks, construction of a
students home, an electro-chemical factory, a sugar factory, etc. - were all
held to promote 'public purpose', and the land acquisition by the state for
these enterprises upheld.
Further
modifications were made to the law during the Indira Gandhi regime by the Land
Acquisition (Amendment) Act 1984. This provided some minor relief for persons
whose land was to be acquired in the form of an improved solatium, and some
time limits on the acquisition process. However, the major demand heard over
the years, that 'public purpose' be clearly and unambiguously defined and
limited in the law, was not addressed. Instead, the inclusive definition of
'public purpose' was widened to include acquisition of land for 'planned
development' and subsequent sale to private enterprise. With this, the death
knell for original possessors of land was completely rung; once the government
set eyes on someone's land and intended to acquire it, it mattered very little
what the purpose was.
This enormous
power available to governments led to many blatant abuses. For example, the
West Bengal Government acquired level fertile agricultural land in West
Medinipur for Tata Metaliks in 1992, leading to dispossessing small and
marginal farmers, in preference to undulating wasteland that was available
nearby. In the case of the Century Textiles Pig Iron Plant in the same area,
the state government acquired about 525 acres of land for a proposed plant in
1996. However, till 2003 the factory had not come up and neither had all the
original land owners been fully compensated; the company had decided that pig
iron production was no longer profitable and refused to pay the compensation
and take over the land .
Singur is
another example of the same government acquiring prime agricultural land for a
car factory, in this case, for Tata Motors. State governments have not
hesitated to acquire land even (mis)using draconian emergency powers available
in the Land Acquisition Act. A case in point is the Tamilnadu government's
acquisition of land near Pulicat Lake north of Chennai for a petro-chemical
complex.
01 October 2007
No comments:
Post a Comment